The PRC became committed to a policy of managed marketisation and globalisation in 1987, which was termed ‘capitalism with Chinese characteristics.’ In the decades since, economic growth has lifted more people from poverty than at any other time in history, contributed to the development of global growth, and added a third engine to global markets after North America and Europe. As China is resource-poor, its spending of surplus dollars gained in trade on African and South American markets has also lifted those areas for the first time from the dependency and postcolonial malaise identified by the Brandt Commission in 1980. Western Europe, and particularly Britain, have benefitted from Chinese investment and tourism, and have reached a position of trade balance as European and British products have been sold to the Chinese middle classes.
The
immediate ‘challenges’ of such growth have largely been to western institutions
and wages. In the longue durée, China’s growth, and that of other East
Asian states earlier in the twentieth and twenty-first century, such as Korea,
Japan, Vietnam, and Thailand, have been based around lower wages, property
booms, and close relationships with western capital and manufacturing
industries in joint ventures. These have removed manufacturing jobs from the
West, placed pressure on wages, and gradually inflated energy and raw material
costs. This has contributed to a fall in the very high western living standards
which prevailed from the late 1940s to the 1970s, though western monetary
policies and lack of productivity are also to blame.
This
process is in part reflective of the return of the world economy to ‘normalcy’
after the growth of Western Empires. For most of human history, East Asia, the
Eastern Mediterranean, and Central America were areas of great wealth. This was
transferred by outright theft and the application of technological supremacy on
the part of Western Europe and its splinter societies from the eighteenth to
the twentieth centuries. That a recovery could be effected within half a
century, in large part powered by the PRC, is remarkable.
There
are downsides to China’s growth, however. Many more people are now alive than
were alive in previous centuries. Therefore, if the PRC with over four times
the population of the USA alone aspires to American living standards, it must
acquire sources of energy, food, and raw materials greater than those currently
available to it. Whilst this might create great pressure to innovate, and
result in the development of new methods of development, there are very few
miracle cures. Neither the Harrod-Domar, Swann-Solow, Rostow, or globalisation
models of growth allow for infinite resources.
It
follows that China could develop on a path in which it accumulates reserve
currency such as the US dollar and euro by trade, spends it on resource
acquisition in Africa and Asia, but then attempts to replace the dollar with
Yuan. This would lead to turmoil in global markets and a reaction by
dollar-based companies and economies which could result in the development of
rival currency blocs and trade zones.
Secondly,
China could follow the same path as Korea and Japan. This was one of rapid
development, followed by demographic collapse as populations aged, property
values fell or stagnated, and a greater and greater burden of taxation and
dependency was placed on fewer and fewer young people. Under such
circumstances, Chinese producers, pension funds, and capital markets, could
find that diminishing marginal returns and diseconomies of scale set in rapidly
and growth could turn into deflation on an historically unprecedented scale.
This fall in consumption in China could then be transmitted to Chinese trading
partners, and to a need to make Chinese investments in property and business
elsewhere deliver, further lowering western incomes and living standards.
Thirdly,
the most obvious places from which China could acquire resources rapidly are
Siberia and South-east Asia. With ASEAN and trans-pacific bodies, plus the USA,
limiting China’s ability to acquire resources in south-east Asia, Siberia,
Canada, Australia, and South America might become key sources for China. A
‘belt and road’ strategy of gaining resources in Africa and Siberia could
encourage the PRC to attempt to denominate resources in Roubles, East African
Shillings, or Yuan in such as way that the global economy reverses and splits
into a ‘Euro/dollar’ area and an Eastern one. This will lower global allocative
efficiency, increase duplication, and create resource tension at a level which
mixes politics and economics and which would exclude Australia, Canada, and New
Zealand from any Chinese-led bloc.
If
the USA were deprived of the reserve status of the dollar as a global currency
which large numbers of people wished to hold, the US would find funding the US
national debt and deficit much more difficult than is currently the case. This
would result in the decline of American purchasing power and aggregate demand,
and an inflation in countries tied financially to American and domestic and eurodollar
markets. The net result could be stagflation,
Fourthly,
China’s growth could result in greater inequality inside the PRC, and the
growth of global negative ecological externalities arising from China. These
could include pollution, waste, global climate problems, and a slowdown in
supply chains as strikes and western disinvestment from areas perceived to
exploit workers began to bite.
In challenges
are opportunities, however. China has largely followed a Lewis model of
economic growth and has passed the inflection point during which export-led
growth is replaced by internal rebalancing and the development of a large
tertiary sector. It has also managed the gradual global expansion of the Yuan
without allowing the development of destabilising inward flows of capital or
dependence on western banks, as Russia failed to do in 1990-1999. China is also
still in control of its own strategic industries, since its growth was based on
joint ventures rather than multinational control of its economy. In coming
years, population pressures will slow. China still maintains an highly
educated, relatively cheap, and very productive class of workers.
Given such
‘upsides’ the challenge of Chinese growth could be accompanied by the
development of new technologies, new patterns of energy use, and innovation on
an unprecedented scale. Chinese growth could also power the extension of the
global economy into space beyond the satellite market, and onto the moon and
planets, leading to a boom in materials and economies comparable to the
industrial revolution. China could sponsor a new ‘Green Revolution’ in the
development of food supplies comparable to the original one, which proved
Malthus wrong. Its turn into more expensive forms of steel, capital, and
machinery could raise Chinese wages and in itself rebalance the global mismatch
between high western costs and lower Chinese ones which caused helped cause
disinvestment and deindustrialisation in the west. This, along with smaller
populations, might help structural and cyclical unemployment in the west.
The challenge of
China to financial markets, particularly if it sponsors a BRICS-based ‘special
drawing right’ currency against the dollar or simply floats the Yuan, could
also be good for Western economies like Britain and the USA. The former would
be forced to become more focussed on manufacturing, productivity, and domestic
growth rather than the derivative and financial markets of the London-New York
axis, and the latter would be forced to try to lower its vast nominal national
debt and budget deficits. These are still recoverable as US debt: GDP ratios
are not at practical or mathematical levels where debt destruction by
hyperinflation or forgiveness are the only options. A global challenge which
made private debt less available and forced fiscal limits on the federal
government whilst raising interest rates on new debt would not necessarily be a
bad thing. Competition is good. American, British,
African, Asian, and South American innovation might grow from competition and challenge
after a period of pain.
The world
economy is ‘owned.’ It is a congeries of banks, multinational corporations,
governments, and international bodies which make it work. Work, production, and
value, however, is derived from the productivity and growth produced by human
beings. No one country or area has any right to that ownership, so it follows
that ‘the challenge of China’ is a way of talking about the return to normalcy
of China within the world economy. Such a challenge might herald a period of
great human growth and prosperity so long as it is focussed on equitable
technological development within ecological limits. If it is based on reckless
exploitation, then diminishing marginal returns, stagflation, and temporary
ecological or demographic collapse leading to resource wars will ultimately end
the challenge, whilst making everyone poorer.
Comments
Post a Comment