Income
inequality arises when different consumers have different incomes, and
different people have different talents. It could also arise because of the
source of income or the value of the talents. For instance, employees might
have different incomes from each other because of
different marginal labour products, different factor returns to their labour,
or different elasticities of labour. People might have different skills for
which there is a greater or lesser need and employers, or the purchasers of labour
might have different demands.
Equally,
entrepreneurs often take greater risks than others, and thereby expect and
receive greater rewards than those who do not take risks. There might be
different factor returns to capital or land, which result in various levels of profit, dividend, or rent, for those
who do not live by the return to their labour value. A functional market would
bring all these diverse groups together as
suppliers and consumers and would match their combined effective demand with
actual supply.
The
existence of inequality also allows for innovation, adaptation, and growth on
the part of companies. This innovation reflects the dynamic nature of markets.
A market in which a few people or companies receive most of the income is not
guaranteed to last. IBM fell from dominance. So will Google, Amazon, and
Twitter, unless governments act to ‘protect’ the
public which result in barriers to entry arising for any competitors.
The
Kuznets curve, and the Lewis model of development, both suggest that people in
poor countries might abandon land in agricultural areas or sell it, move to
areas where their productivity is higher, and accept a temporarily lower
standard of living so long as their productivity is rewarded by higher incomes
which allow them to save. At some point, they will rise in income and wealth,
and the gap between them and the previously very wealthy will close. Things
change.
If
the growth of the economy in such circumstances is export-led and accompanied
by mild but consistent inflation, which lowers the fixed returns to those who
own assets or land whilst empowering those who receive wages, workers will be
rewarded according to their talents.
Even
in the allocatively and productively efficient model of perfect competition,
economists assume that companies wish to gain abnormal profit, raising the
returns to their owners and allowing for a degree of differentiation in income
and wealth. This is done by finding ways either to lower average cost and
marginal cost in production, or to raise revenues through advertising,
marketing, or the development of differentiated products.
In the long run,
this is a good and dynamic thing, not a market failure, because the rewards
which can be gained from the competition and innovation advance society towards
more efficient allocation and production. Consumers get the benefit of more
supply, at lower real prices given rising incomes. As
societies become richer and savings and wealth advance, a functional financial
centre can also provide credit and investment markets and products at a steady
real rate of interest which can help people leverage their assets and ideas.
Problems
arise when suppliers and the owners of capital and land are allowed to raise
barriers to entry, or when markets are distorted by government policies or
cartels. This can result in a situation in which oligopolies and monopolies
arise. If these oligopolies and monopolies are allowed to develop monopsony
power, they will capture the labour value of workers and will not reward effort.
Instead, workers will be held to lower wages with a higher level of
unemployment.
In
such circumstances, innovation, and business growth
outside of the oligopolies will be discouraged because there will be lower
credit, lower savings, and less investment outside of the big companies. The
companies themselves will integrate vertically and horizontally, leading to
economies of scale which deliver greater and greater returns to fewer and fewer
owners, whose sheer wealth and market power will be barriers to entry towards
any small player.
Those
on lower incomes will rely increasingly on giffen
goods like rented property, which will be more in demand as property becomes
more expensive. Real disposable income will be lower, as will growth, leading
to a dependence on low welfare payments, low tax income, and limited
governments dependent on borrowing. The market will come to be characterised by
inferior goods for the majority, and luxury goods for the rich and foreign
consumers of great wealth.
If
such a situation arises, capitalism and the prosperity that comes from
enterprise, saving, small business, property ownership, and innovation and
competition will turn into a system of rent-seeking oligopolies and cartels
owned by a few extraordinarily rich people or families.
Such economies will lose their competitive edge, and increasingly will approach
their terms of trade as a matter of tying low-wage labour to exports. This will
lead to productivity gains and improved competitiveness, but at the cost of
negative externalities like pollution, low saving, and higher domestic prices
for normal goods.
In
these circumstances, income inequality will reinforce a market failure. Like the idea of vice, one failure will lead to
others. Cartels will become reinforcing, suffocating small companies, and buying up or copying those which manage
to start up, preventing savings, allowing for the whims of the very rich to override sensible investment and
improvement, and trapping everyone in a world of low
returns, unaffordable prices, and low growth.
The
appropriate solution is to raise taxes on unearned wealth and inheritance, and
to raise marginal tax rates on the very wealthy. This should be accompanied by
stable real interest rates and a policy of balancing the budget, either over
the economic cycle or immediately, and low debt. Then, gradually, the economy
will become prosperous, competitive, and
entrepreneurial.
Unfortunately,
governments have a tendency not to pursue such policies but instead to
intervene in markets in ways which lead to distortion and new market and
government failures. For instance, to cope with the
unreasonable prices and monopolistic behaviour of
natural monopolies such as railways or energy providers, governments might
introduce ‘price caps,’ artificial market forces via franchises and RPI-K
pricing formulas, and subsidy which distort markets, depress research and
development, and which are open to regulatory capture.
Governments
can suffer from decision failure where, for example, they identify a problem
which is not static but dynamic, take time to develop a solution, then take
more time to implement it. By the end of the process, the original problem
might have disappeared and been replaced by another one.
One justification for government policy to reduce income inequality, for
instance, is the way that energy prices in a distorted market can become
regressive and hurt vulnerable groups. Often, the ‘solution’ is not to deal
with the inequality, but to further distort the energy prices (a feature of
policy in agricultural markets too.)
When
oil and gas were abundant and cheap in the global market, Britain had a surfeit
of coal and nuclear power. So, ministers concentrated on removing the surplus
in the name of efficiency and the environment, whilst guaranteeing cheap
prices. This took several decades and resulted in a deficit of energy, a world
of predictably high power prices, structural
unemployment, and a reliance on ‘green growth’ which was something of a
delusion. The energy system was also ‘capped’ in ways that discouraged the
development of storage systems and encouraged rent-seeking companies to buy up
cheap international energy to sell at a profit, which was presented as
‘enterprise’ and encouraged until the rent-seeking companies went bankrupt, and the energy market became a cartel
distorted by government subsidies and rules. Pensioners
and the poor were colder and more vulnerable, nor warmer and safer at the end
of the process.
Similarly,
energy companies were forced to charge in such a way that returns to ‘green’
energy suppliers were great whilst those to fossil-fuel sources were small and
non-existent to nuclear providers. This was achieved by a marginal pricing
formula for energy which added expensive green power to cheap gas and nuclear
costs. When gas and nuclear rose, ‘green’ power was still soaking up this
subsidy, but was not able to provide an energy uplift, transmission of power
across distances, or storage of power. All these measures were tied to the need to ensure
cheap power because of income inequality in a distorted market of financialised
products, high house prices fuelled by lending, and waste. Governments chose
the wrong policies.
Policies
focussed on allowing only a small but widely rewarding amount of inequality,
steady real interest rates, high marginal taxation on unearned capital gains,
steady tax income rather than the encouragement of tax avoidance, and lower
taxes for the majority with higher and steadier taxes on the wealth and income
of the very rich, would have been much better.
Public-private ownership of nationalised natural monopolies which allowed for
some private returns on the provision of public and merit goods, maintaining
security and low prices, would have been better than false ‘markets’ based on
franchises and over-complex regulation which needed and encouraged high prices to create a return for shareholders.
Pensions and financial regulation which encouraged saving, and which subsidised
health insurance rather than a vast monopoly NHS employing over a million
people at low wages and rent-seeking GP franchises would have tackled income
inequality and low savings in every town and city.
Income
inequality is not therefore a necessary market failure. It might be useful, in
a balanced and moderate amount, to markets and society. Government intervention
is not necessarily a solution if the policies
employed are stupid and destructive, or uninformed by economic logic. Very
often, the wrong policies to tackle income inequality would make income
inequality and problems of access to normal goods and energy a consequence of
government failure. The regulation of companies is also prone to regulatory
capture and government’s demonstrated comfort with bigger rather than smaller
companies (a failure noticed by public choice theory.)
Income
inequality in lesser amounts is tolerable, and a
good thing. It is better than other market failures such as pollution, the
over-provision and under-pricing of demerit goods, and distorted market
structures. Equally, larger, and more destructive
income inequality can be part of a parcel of government failures created by
poor or lagged government decisions, moral hazard (for instance in the case of
reckless bank lending where states guarantee banks) and externalities created
by government choice and public choice theory.
Comments
Post a Comment