Skip to main content

When, if ever, is it a good idea for governments and central banks to set interest rates at ultra-low or negative levels?

 

Ultra-low interest policies have been a feature of global monetary management since 2008 in most countries (and were tried in Japan before that.) They exist in the context of the near-collapse of the global economy and of national and international banking, credit, and derivative markets in 2008, though they also reflect a perceived lack of inflation risk. The idea behind ultra-low interest rates, or negative real or nominal rates, was, firstly, to prevent a credit crunch.

Credit crunches happen when banks have lent out a great deal of money and cannot fund a large volume of withdrawals. This causes banks to reduce refinancing and new lending, which puts individuals and businesses in a position where they cannot stay in the market and pay their bills and debts, thus creating a spiral of economic decline. In addition, banks might in such circumstances start asking for their loans and credit payments back early, worsening things still further.

Many modern banks also are principally mortgage lenders. If they have equity in housing as a lender, but then a credit crunch means that people cannot take out new mortgages or pay existing ones, banks lose share value. They lose profits. The demand for housing collapses, worsening the process. Ultimately, savers might queue to close accounts and withdraw money, at the same time as borrowers face restrictions and banks face crisis. This is how depressions start.

There is very little resilience in the modern economy, which across the developed world is based on various forms of sophisticated individual and corporate debt. Low central bank interest rates allow for liquidity on the part of banks which borrow from the centre, create a sense of security and stability for those banks (and some pension and hedge funds) and therefore keep the system going. One problem is that there is still a great deal of risk in the economy, since structural unemployment, a lack of ownership, property, transferable skills, or savings amongst the population, and economies used to high consumer spending and rents, still exists.

This means that the ‘excess’ liquidity caused by low or negative rates, which discourage saving, turns into ‘safe’ lending to those who already have money or property, which then worsens the gap between rich and poor and makes the poor and small businesses more dependent on credit and borrowing. It discourages saving too, and encourages spending, which can create inflation, but which also deprives businesses and entrepreneurs of incentives to invest. Those who have money then tend to invest it in ‘bubbles’ or, if they are public limited companies, to inflate the apparent value of their shares by buying them back themselves. Eventually, an inflationary scenario develops in which expectations change, people respond to the threat of inflation by buying up stores of value (like gold, silver, and bitcoin) and the velocity of money increases. Velocity of money means the desire to get rid of cash and to replace it with something which delivers a greater return than saving, and explains why, after a big reduction in interest rates and an expansion of cash, construction costs are soaring in the USA and house demand is rising massively in the UK.

Trying to force economic growth and development with an emergency policy which should have been time-limited is like becoming addicted to medical steroids or medical opioids. It is a currency debasement which has always led to inflationary surges. Great Inflations, even hyperinflations, are not always bad things in the abstract; they ‘reboot’ societies, remind people of the importance of saving, crash economies that do not make things that people want, and demolish dangerous financial practices for several decades. They also rebalance inequality, and some societies have benefitted from them in the long run (Weimar Germany escaped many of the burdens of the Treaty of Versailles, the inequalities of the French Ancien Regime were assaulted, the eastern European market democracies gained a balanced set of prices which actually worked in 1991, and Venezuela is being discouraged from economic lunacy, for instance). In the short run, however, they are terrible, and require sympathetic and internationally organised coordinated rescues or protection for those citizens, particularly the most dependent or vulnerable, who are affected by them.

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Domestic Demand, External Pressures, and Inflation

    Domestic Demand refers to the accumulated (that is, aggregate) demand within all the markets of an economy. As such, it can be handily summed up in a formula, C+I+G+X-M, where C is consumption, I is investment, G is net government spending, and X-M is net exports. This is usually referred to as ‘AD.’ Consumption is the largest part of AD. All the consumption decisions within the economy, including all non-investment purchases by households, individuals, and firms, add up to around two thirds of AD. In addition, the Keynesian economic theory asserts that there is a link between consumption and investment, which can drive AD upwards, as firms invest more when they see that consumers are purchasing more goods and services. Investment is a sustained addition to long-run aggregate supply, or capital for short. AD can be plotted against LRAS on a two-dimensional graph. If AD and LRAS meet at the point where there is maximum real GDP/GNI with no tendency for the price level to rise, t

Understanding the Balance of Payments

The balance of payments is the measure of all economic transactions between an economy and the rest of the world. As such, it covers the whole economy and should not be confused with the Government Budget. The balance of payments must always balance and if there is a deficit or surplus in goods, services, or some other component of the balance, it will be met with an equal change in the value of money or other asset. In a free exchange market, for instance, the currency of the country will adjust to alter living standards and the source of any surplus or deficit. The balance of payments consists of a current account, known as the balance of trade , a financial account , and a capital account. The current account is a record of net exports, plus income from abroad and direct transfers into a country. Many countries, particularly in the English-speaking world, run a deficit on this current account, because consumers and businesses purchase more imports than exports. This may well

Higher Energy Prices and The Economy

  Energy prices are a basic cost. They are semi-variable for most businesses, in that a basic fixed cost of energy is generated by the need to heat or to cool buildings, and to carry out operations. In addition, a marginal cost exists for producers in terms of the energy required to increase production. Finally, energy costs are also built into the transport of raw materials, and the distribution of finished goods and services, which again contribute to marginal costs. If global energy prices are rising wholesale, it is unlikely that businesses or individuals will be able to lower the retail cost of energy by switching between suppliers. Energy storage is expensive and encourages economies of scale and oligopolies, in which consumer choice is limited at times of higher wholesale prices. When energy prices are low, smaller companies can purchase wholesale and make money at the margin undercutting bigger companies as storage costs will be a burden for the latter and the small companies