A firm is an economic entity engaged in business. Economic theory assumes that the firm, like the consumer, maximises its self-interest. This self interest is however the product of the interplay of market structure, business organisation, and chosen or required objective. So, for instance, some firms might choose to profit-maximise, some to profit satisfy, some to revenue maximise, and some to sales-maximise, or even engage in loss-leading predatory behaviours. Oligopoly firms might take their cue from other firms, and find that price-maximisation is only really possible if they can join a cartel; imperfectly competitive firms might sustain a loss in the short run, covering their variable costs and making a contribution to fixed ones, if they think that this will lead to ultimate survival in a temporarily tough market.
These
decisions often relate to the nature of the firms. A sole trader’s objective,
for instance, may include the freedom and control that working for oneself can
bring. The directors of private limited companies (plcs), who are not under the
immediate threat that lower profits will lead to the sale of their shares and
who have to give permission for share sales anyway, might choose to maximise
status or to profit-satisfy for family or company reasons—for instance wanting
to remain associated with a particular area or group of workers. A public
limited company would be forced to prioritise profits and profit maximising
behaviour (producing where marginal cost equals marginal revenue) or risk
takeover.
Technically,
firms can accept ‘normal’ profit, which is the profit needed to cover
opportunity cost, and evident in perfect competition in the long run. Actually,
most firms would want an abnormal profit, in which average revenue exceeded average
costs. Whilst this takes from consumer profit and the overall efficiency of production,
it provides the incentive for business and entrepreneurial behaviour and is a
reward for business effort.
Abnormal
profit also indicates to owners that the business is doing well. This can
create confidence, encourage purchasing managers to put money into the economy,
maintain or increase employment, and provide the funds for investment. Even
where normal profit is the norm, in perfect competition, firms have an
incentive to develop ideas or to quickly apply cost-savings measures, given
that they cannot influence consumers or affect supply or demand, so as to make
a temporary abnormal profit in the short run.
Weight
needs to be given to the idea of the principal-agent problem in economics. This
assumes that there is a split between ownership and control in business, which
is most evident in plcs. In such firms, directors need to account to owners.
Even in a private limited company (ltd) some directors are more active than
others, and sole traders are often accountable to their banks, who are powerful
as owners in some ways and who can end the business by withdrawing credit if
there is no consistent or credible path to profit.
Revenue
maximisation can lead to an abnormal profit, just a lower one than
profit-maximisation. Revenue maximising behaviour occurs where a firm wishes to
get as much cash as possible and to sell surplus stock for any marginal profit
at a price where marginal revenue is at 0. This is not a way of life for firms,
but might be a regular choice. So, for instance, a limited company in a
recessionary environment, or one in which consumers are under income pressure,
might choose to launch sales on a rolling basis or to exploit differences
between wholesale sourcing and retail sales in order to move goods off shelves
as quickly as possible.
Similarly,
larger monopoly companies with complementary products might choose to sell some
of them at a point where average cost equals average revenue. This makes for no
abnormal profit at all, but does maximise sales in a way which could be
intimidatory for firms.
Sometimes,
too, firms cannot easily calculate marginal revenue and cost, and will accept a
certain level of profit below the maximum. This might also be because the firm is
part of a wider supply chain or embedded in practices which require activities
that cannot be simply audited or costed. A football club, for instance, is a
kind of company, and very much has shareholders and financial requirements. Funds
are intimately linked to popularity with fans, which in almost every case is
linked to success on the playing field, leading to gate receipts and
participation in leagues with lucrative media sales.
If
a football firm (or any major sports enterprise) did not invest in players and
the culture of training, and in relationships with its supporters beyond
merchandise and ticket sales, it would lose support and probably see a decline
in marginal revenue productivity of players. This would be true even if the
firm had enough money on hand to simply ‘buy’ the best players from anywhere. It
follows that a policy of simple profit-maximisation in such circumstances holds
the potential to be destructive to the firm.
Many
firms are also concerned with their social responsibilities or their
relationship with consumers in terms of image. Whole Foods, for instance, and
to an extent ‘high end’ supermarkets like Waitrose attract and keep customers
on the basis of product differentiation and quality. This requires them to
avoid being seen to compete on price, and should discourage them from adopting
the profit-maximising behaviours of firms in other parts of the market. If such
firms were to become associated with damaging environmental practices or supply
chain issues which conflicted with the beliefs of their customers, they might
find themselves losing core revenue without adding any customers to compensate.
British
markets tend to be marked out by small firms which are barely making above normal
profit in imperfect competition, oligopolies such as those in banks, coffee
shops, sports companies, and supermarkets, which are operating at a profit-satisficing
point somewhere around the ‘kink’ in their AR (‘Demand’) curve, and privatised
natural monopolies whose prices and profits have been distorted by government
regulations. Although profits are often high, they are not always at a maximum.
This
is because of political economy; the government and consumers must be choosing
to accept this form of settlement. Should a firm go ‘all-out’ to
profit-maximise, it would become subject to calls for a ‘windfall tax’ or to claims
upon its social responsibility. Even in American markets, ‘price gouging’ is
not fully tolerated, which is why Martin Shkreli is jail despite operating in
the infamously price-maximising pharmaceutical industry. Profit-maximisers can
often, in Britain and America, attract regulatory or political attention which,
oddly, gives agents of the firm, or occasionally principals, an odd potential
cost of fines, unpopularity, or jail for profit-maximising.
Comments
Post a Comment