There
are a number of ways to refer to the supply of labour. A precise one is that
the supply is the number willing and able to work within the market at a set of
wage rates for a given time. The supply curve is likely to be upward sloping as
the wage required to maximise the hours people work will increase the more work
that they do unless there is infinite elasticity of supply.
There
are across the developed world intense pressures on the supply of labour. In
part, this is because of immigration restrictions which place barriers on the
movement of people globally, so that national or regional labour markets are
inelastic in supply. Another ‘global’ reason is the intense and accelerating
decline in birth rates, which fell some time ago, or which are falling, to
below replacement rates.
This
process means that there are fewer young people entering the workforce, and
more older people in society. That in turn means that, in Japan, Korea, or
Italy, for example, there is a greater dependency of the old and welfare and
healthcare systems on the earnings of all workers, as well as on the
productivity of the economy. The consequence is that, in affected countries,
taxes will rise, or service provision will fall, or retirement ages will be
extended to later in life. There will also be a changing opportunity cost of labour
with regard to capital, as wages rise because positions are not filled. A cost-push effect on the economy could lead
to a stagflationary environment.
In the early 1970s, western labour markets began to change as technology changed. This led to a growth in female employment and service industries, and to the ancillary services such as childcare, care homes, and the production of domestic goods which replaced a model in which married men funded multi-member households with industrial work. The change accompanied cost-push inflation and the energy crisis, to which the West and then the world responded with financialisation. This process is now not repeatable and is at an end, with market saturation of supply, and the implications for higher wages and tighter employment markets run alongside the stagflationary environment. In such circumstances, gender discrimination is not in most developed societies a satisfactory explanation for labour market rigidities.
As
well as population and net immigration, labour markets are affected by barriers
such as labour immobility. This could arise from geographical factors, such as
the difficulty of locating affordable housing in areas of job growth, or
problems in transport. In some economies, the existence of language or cultural
barriers may impact upon the availability of labour or of labour to move from
areas of unemployment to areas of job availability.
People
being people, there are also ‘trade offs’ between leisure and work. These are
sometimes confused with three other trade-offs, partly because the term
‘voluntary unemployment’ is ambiguous. Sometimes, childcare costs, or the costs
of looking after an ill relative or a household by employing others are so high
that work is not a rational economic choice. Leaving the workforce and staying
at home in such circumstances, provided a family income from elsewhere can be
obtained, does maximise utility. This might be complemented by a welfare system
that does not encourage work, or by a type of union control of jobs which
‘locks out’ non-union members and lowers the number of jobs available because
of high wages.
It
is possible that better working conditions and high wages, or a liveable
minimum wage, allow for a greater supply of labour, with higher
productivity. This is because people might want to work in such conditions and
find that their trade-off changes. It would not change the demand calculation
of workers versus machinery unless the new workers were cheaper in some way
than the existing workforce, or more productive.
Younger
and older societies tend to have different interpretations of leisure time.
Younger people might wish to maximise work time and to accrue every marginal
benefit from work during working hours, and then have the stamina to sustain a
night-time or evening leisure economy, or short breaks paid for by a
combination of work and credit made available by work. Middle aged and older
societies may prefer higher wages for fewer hours, and to extend breaks and
part-time working.
These
differences suggest that dynamic labour markets might be ones which contain
different contracts and terms of employment. By contrast, rigid labour markets
in which the bulk of people work at the same hours for common modal incomes on
the same basis with the same conditions might be more rigid and inelastic in
the supply of labour.
The
tax and welfare system can have a serious effect on the supply of labour. For
instance, marginal tax rates could affect the decision of individuals about
whether they seek work and for how long. The tax rates on self-employment and
the ease by which people could be self-employed might also matter in those
circumstances.
Finally,
the availability of apprenticeships and training, and the nature of individual
and household debt might affect the supply of labour. Many people in the modern
workforce require a job to obtain credit, and to meet the minimum payments on
credit cards, for instance. Many graduate disposable incomes are low, because
debts of several sorts and the expansion of graduate supply mean that there is
less return than there once was to many degrees. This may mean that in the
future, fewer people enter university, and that an oversupply of graduates
turns into a market rigidity.
There
is much less union membership in the twenty-first century UK labour market than
there was for most of the twentieth. This means that unions are not as able to
act as monopoly controllers of labour, and of course unions cannot enforce
membership through closed shop agreements. Union power to strike or engage in
restrictive practices has also been severely curtailed.
In
natural monopolies such as the London underground, however, and in government
and state schools, union membership is still high and union militancy is still
a constraint on labour. This situation is in contrast with, for instance, the
non-unionised position of warehouse workers. Even where there are high levels
of trade membership, however, as amongst nurses in the NHS, unions have not
been able to realise significant increases in pay.
Successive
British governments have pursued different strategies to encourage employment
and greater market supply. After the restriction of union power in the
eighties, for instance, labour markets were deregulated further between 1990
and 2010. Welfare systems, which once experimented with family allowances and
state provision of childcare, moved through tax credits and incentives for work
to universal credit, which is predicated upon work as the norm. The national
minimum wage, which is differentiated by age, has been adapted to the idea of a
national living wage. The income tax system has been simplified, as has that
for self-employment, compared to previous versions. Zero-hours contracts have been introduced and
are now a settled part of some employment sectors.
Technology
is also changing the requirements of employers and the supply of labour, in
that online shopping, for instance, requires workers with very little training
to simply either shop or transport goods. As with other forms of tech-based
employment, this allows workers to offer themselves for long or short periods,
on a minimum-conditions basis, and sometimes even to provide (as with uber)
their own capital equipment. This elastic and flexible new workforce, however,
has very little opportunity for economic mobility, career and occupational
progression, savings, or the accumulation of pensions or seniority, and faces a
lower average wage than the full-time employed.
Marginal
‘odd jobs’ to make ends meet have become occupations, in a way that is not
ultimately good for productivity or society, not least because the same
technology which allows for more supermarket jobs also allows general
practitioners and lecturers to deliver a worse service online, encourages GPs
to work fewer days a week, and degrades the provision of taxpayer funded merit
goods whilst encouraging the state to stint on investment in human resources.
Barristers have seen great falls in income in criminal courts, for instance, as
technology has led the Ministry of Justice to think about smart scheduling of
cases and to offload case preparation onto fees-based workers so that employees
in the crown prosecution service are rated as efficient.
Making
labour markets less rigid in such ways has consequences. One is the creation of
a ‘precariat’ who have funded their skills by loans, who have low disposable
incomes, and who will seek occupational mobility or emigration if they can.
This will, ultimately, create productivity gains for a short period, as in
academic non-tenured teaching circuits, but at the long-term expense of the
sectors involved and of goodwill and society.
Comments
Post a Comment