The
theory of oligopoly is focussed on a stable market in which a few large firms
dominate the supply of items and can have power over price or supply. This may
be because of economies of scale or high barriers to entry. Barriers to entry
can include sunk costs, legal and regulatory protections and requirements such
as patents or performance rules, and resource availability.
Within
such a market, the theory assumes that the Demand curve for the individual
firms corresponds to their Average revenue curves. These lines are ‘kinked.’
This means that the AR is inelastic and stable below a certain price point,
because customers are not purchasing below the kink based on price, and elastic
above the point, because the customers are price sensitive.
Very
few oligopoly models assume that the AR line is vertical below the kink, which
means that there is some scope for different prices at different levels of
output. Given that customers are highly inelastic, any price cuts would
nevertheless result in losses as the company would gain less in new customers
than it lost in existing revenue. Therefore, once the ‘kink’ in the market was
identified, prices would be likely to remain at or near it, making the whole
market price effectively rigid.
Oligopolies
are still capable of competing, but they would do so on the basis of three
constraints.
Firstly,
oligopoly customers tend to remain with one company regardless of price below
the kink because of convenience, some non-price factor like design, recipe, or
habit, or convenience. This gives, for instance, coffee chains an incentive to
develop new styles of coffee and to attract gains at the margin of the market,
but in the knowledge that others will effectively copy or counter them quickly.
Secondly,
oligopoly markets tend to be subject to ‘customer churn.’ This means that
customers can be expected to leave one company and join others at roughly
similar levels for all companies in the oligopoly. One mobile telephony company
might expect to lose, for instance, five to ten per cent of its own customers
per year, but to gain five to ten per cent of those who have left other large
producers, and vice versa. Therefore, no company has any real incentive to
alter prices to keep existing customers, though there might be some marginal
gain in changing for new ones. This again means that prices are likely to be
largely but not wholly rigid.
Thirdly,
competition in the form of a ‘price war’ only makes sense for oligopolists if
they judge that one of their members is likely to be unable to sustain a period
of lower or no profits. Cutting prices drives marginal revenue down rapidly
when AR is kinked, and if a company has maintained higher costs than others, it
will make losses. Newspapers have in the past engaged in such behaviour in order
to eliminate one title, and share the former paper’s readers with each other,
thus boosting revenue. This behaviour does run the risk, however, of making all
customers price-aware and causing them to demand permanently lower prices or to
leave the market where an alternative exists. This is because it breaks the
habitual behaviour of the customers and replaces it with price awareness, as
overcomplicated price discrimination corresponding to price-gouging by
eliminating consumer surplus might also do.
Oligopolists
are typically aware of such dangers, and many therefore make decisions on the
basis of game theory in which the second-best strategy of everyone maintaining
profits by making no move on prices is a normal outcome. If one company does
decide to start changing price, oligopolists using game theory must decide
either to minimise their maximum loss, maximise their gain, or stay put. The
‘Nash equilibrium’ of everyone doing the second-choice thing is, most of the
time, the most rational, which makes prices look rigid.
It
is therefore not the case that oligopoly prices are necessarily rigid, but it
benefits oligopolists if they are. This is why oligopolists are interdependent
and tend to form cartels to fix prices. A cartel, in which large companies can
tacitly or openly collude to keep prices at a cetain point, eliminates the need
to invest in detailed analysis and game theory-based decisions about the
behaviour of others. the problem is
that, in most domestic markets (but not between governments, as with OPEC)
cartels are illegal, and attract the attention of regulators like the sector
bodies such as Ofgem, national groups like the Financial Conduct Authority, the
government of the PRC, and the US FBI, or supranational groups like the
European Commission. Fines and sanctions from such groups can be intense. Some
variation on prices between companies is therefore sensible when potential
costs are considered.
Finally,
prices are unlikely in any market to be rigid in the long run when barriers to
entry can be circumvented or lapse. Technology, the time limit on patents and
copyrights, and the ability of global companies to overwhelm domestically
dominant firms, tends to mean that no oligopoly lasts forever even if
politicians are suborned by corruption or protectionism. Therefore, prices will
eventually return to an allocatively efficient point, even if there is no
government intervention.
Comments
Post a Comment