Skip to main content

How will government intervention to protect employees affect business behaviour?

 

Employees can be protected by government intervention from the behaviour of businesses in a number of ways. Governments could, for instance, set minimum levels of pay, holiday entitlement, and protected sick leave for employees. They could define the processes whereby employees are disciplined or dismissed.

Governments could regulate the entitlement to healthcare, pensions, or insurance of employees in such a way as to protect employees. They could set minimum redundancy standards for employees who were being laid off. They could protect employees whose business was transferred to another employer because of a merger or takeover. They could set rest periods, define times when employees were not expected to work, and attempt to balance the power of employers against employees so that the latter were not in an impossible position.

Governments could also intervene to guarantee a right to trade union membership, to strike, to protest against company policies, not to be subjected to restrictive rules during or after employment, and to be free of excessive and harassing management, workplace bullying, unsafe conditions, irrational requests, and excessive attempts to surveil and control employees. Governments could seek to protect employees via the law from discrimination.

All of these potential or actual government interventions in the employment market have the effect of adding costs in terms of time and human resources capacity to firms. They might do so without any link to the output size of firms—small employers with relatively low outputs might not be exempt—and would therefore be fixed costs. Fixed costs decline on average as a firm gets bigger by output, and so the restrictions on employers would create an advantage for larger employers for which the cost of compliance would be lower.

If the protections only applied to employees, those who were independent contractors might be forced into higher insurance or left without protection, and firms might be encouraged to hire people on a casual basis.

The way in which the government formulated and applied the protections could create asymmetries and inconsistencies in other ways and could give rise to a legal bureaucracy which stifled innovation or productivity and encouraged employers to move elsewhere. Employers could also pass on higher costs to customers, with a resultant inflation, and further pressures on wages.

The way in which a government acted could also have other, unintended effects. For example, in many economies, the protections listed above were not gained because of government intervention. Governments instead ratified or displaced trades unions, who secured the rights and protections by striking against those companies or monopsonists who were attempting to maximise profits at the expense of their workers.

A monopsonist ‘underpays’ workers, for instance, by paying a wage at the average cost of labour but asking workers to produce at the point where their marginal cost would otherwise meet the marginal revenue product of their labour. In essence, workers are asked by such employers to work harder for less than they deserve in terms of labour value.

Almost all employers divert some labour value, since labour value is the only value added in production apart from the return to an entrepreneur or business for bringing factors together (ultimately a separate form of labour value.) Monopsonist attempt to divert all but the bare minumum and maintain fewer workers than they would employ at normal market prices to keep the threat of unemployment over the workers. If government intervention simply meant that government allowed unions to organise, and protected the right to strike, employers might be encouraged to raise wages to the market equilibrium and employ more people on better terms to ‘stave off’ strikes.

Such a policy could be counter-productive because unions would then have an incentive to push their wages and conditions to the maximum and to ‘lock out’ anyone else. In terms of economic efficiency, legislating for protection at minimal average cost to larger employers could be better for the economy.

Equally, if governments believed that workers were underpaid, or that they were subject to poor life outcomes because of their employment, they could choose to subsidise the workers or create a set of simple minimum standards which did not add to costs. A minimum wage would protect employers and employees from exploitative employers who drove down costs and made jobs effectively into a form of slavery, for instance.

Employers might find that protected workers were more productive and more invested in the company, and that output and revenues rose more quickly than costs. A bare minimum of protections for holiday or sickness pay might not alter the operation of employers who offer more than that in a competitive labour market, and could therefore raise productivity and aggregate demand, and profits, and investment. The proposition that employees should be protected is not therefore immediately one of higher costs.

Even the provision via employers of welfare benefits in addition to pay through national insurance schemes or healthcare and unemployment insurance agreements is potentially something which could improve productivity overall. Such schemes, which tend to work through payments taken directly from wages, represent an efficient form of government intervention in employment markets and are less complicated than tax credits or complicated forms of subsidy.

On this basis, intervention in near-employment markets, such as the provision of broadband so that employees can work productively from home, or the subsidy and regulation of childcare so that the supply of labour expands, are capable of being seen as both protecting employees, boosting productivity, and benefitting employers more than the taxes or minor inflationary pressures involved might increase costs. As in all things, a balanced approach by government in consideration of employers and employees could deliver the conditions for a thriving and more than functional economy.

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Domestic Demand, External Pressures, and Inflation

    Domestic Demand refers to the accumulated (that is, aggregate) demand within all the markets of an economy. As such, it can be handily summed up in a formula, C+I+G+X-M, where C is consumption, I is investment, G is net government spending, and X-M is net exports. This is usually referred to as ‘AD.’ Consumption is the largest part of AD. All the consumption decisions within the economy, including all non-investment purchases by households, individuals, and firms, add up to around two thirds of AD. In addition, the Keynesian economic theory asserts that there is a link between consumption and investment, which can drive AD upwards, as firms invest more when they see that consumers are purchasing more goods and services. Investment is a sustained addition to long-run aggregate supply, or capital for short. AD can be plotted against LRAS on a two-dimensional graph. If AD and LRAS meet at the point where there is maximum real GDP/GNI with no tendency for the price level to rise, t

Understanding the Balance of Payments

The balance of payments is the measure of all economic transactions between an economy and the rest of the world. As such, it covers the whole economy and should not be confused with the Government Budget. The balance of payments must always balance and if there is a deficit or surplus in goods, services, or some other component of the balance, it will be met with an equal change in the value of money or other asset. In a free exchange market, for instance, the currency of the country will adjust to alter living standards and the source of any surplus or deficit. The balance of payments consists of a current account, known as the balance of trade , a financial account , and a capital account. The current account is a record of net exports, plus income from abroad and direct transfers into a country. Many countries, particularly in the English-speaking world, run a deficit on this current account, because consumers and businesses purchase more imports than exports. This may well

Higher Energy Prices and The Economy

  Energy prices are a basic cost. They are semi-variable for most businesses, in that a basic fixed cost of energy is generated by the need to heat or to cool buildings, and to carry out operations. In addition, a marginal cost exists for producers in terms of the energy required to increase production. Finally, energy costs are also built into the transport of raw materials, and the distribution of finished goods and services, which again contribute to marginal costs. If global energy prices are rising wholesale, it is unlikely that businesses or individuals will be able to lower the retail cost of energy by switching between suppliers. Energy storage is expensive and encourages economies of scale and oligopolies, in which consumer choice is limited at times of higher wholesale prices. When energy prices are low, smaller companies can purchase wholesale and make money at the margin undercutting bigger companies as storage costs will be a burden for the latter and the small companies