Skip to main content

How will government intervention to protect employees affect business behaviour?

 

Employees can be protected by government intervention from the behaviour of businesses in a number of ways. Governments could, for instance, set minimum levels of pay, holiday entitlement, and protected sick leave for employees. They could define the processes whereby employees are disciplined or dismissed.

Governments could regulate the entitlement to healthcare, pensions, or insurance of employees in such a way as to protect employees. They could set minimum redundancy standards for employees who were being laid off. They could protect employees whose business was transferred to another employer because of a merger or takeover. They could set rest periods, define times when employees were not expected to work, and attempt to balance the power of employers against employees so that the latter were not in an impossible position.

Governments could also intervene to guarantee a right to trade union membership, to strike, to protest against company policies, not to be subjected to restrictive rules during or after employment, and to be free of excessive and harassing management, workplace bullying, unsafe conditions, irrational requests, and excessive attempts to surveil and control employees. Governments could seek to protect employees via the law from discrimination.

All of these potential or actual government interventions in the employment market have the effect of adding costs in terms of time and human resources capacity to firms. They might do so without any link to the output size of firms—small employers with relatively low outputs might not be exempt—and would therefore be fixed costs. Fixed costs decline on average as a firm gets bigger by output, and so the restrictions on employers would create an advantage for larger employers for which the cost of compliance would be lower.

If the protections only applied to employees, those who were independent contractors might be forced into higher insurance or left without protection, and firms might be encouraged to hire people on a casual basis.

The way in which the government formulated and applied the protections could create asymmetries and inconsistencies in other ways and could give rise to a legal bureaucracy which stifled innovation or productivity and encouraged employers to move elsewhere. Employers could also pass on higher costs to customers, with a resultant inflation, and further pressures on wages.

The way in which a government acted could also have other, unintended effects. For example, in many economies, the protections listed above were not gained because of government intervention. Governments instead ratified or displaced trades unions, who secured the rights and protections by striking against those companies or monopsonists who were attempting to maximise profits at the expense of their workers.

A monopsonist ‘underpays’ workers, for instance, by paying a wage at the average cost of labour but asking workers to produce at the point where their marginal cost would otherwise meet the marginal revenue product of their labour. In essence, workers are asked by such employers to work harder for less than they deserve in terms of labour value.

Almost all employers divert some labour value, since labour value is the only value added in production apart from the return to an entrepreneur or business for bringing factors together (ultimately a separate form of labour value.) Monopsonist attempt to divert all but the bare minumum and maintain fewer workers than they would employ at normal market prices to keep the threat of unemployment over the workers. If government intervention simply meant that government allowed unions to organise, and protected the right to strike, employers might be encouraged to raise wages to the market equilibrium and employ more people on better terms to ‘stave off’ strikes.

Such a policy could be counter-productive because unions would then have an incentive to push their wages and conditions to the maximum and to ‘lock out’ anyone else. In terms of economic efficiency, legislating for protection at minimal average cost to larger employers could be better for the economy.

Equally, if governments believed that workers were underpaid, or that they were subject to poor life outcomes because of their employment, they could choose to subsidise the workers or create a set of simple minimum standards which did not add to costs. A minimum wage would protect employers and employees from exploitative employers who drove down costs and made jobs effectively into a form of slavery, for instance.

Employers might find that protected workers were more productive and more invested in the company, and that output and revenues rose more quickly than costs. A bare minimum of protections for holiday or sickness pay might not alter the operation of employers who offer more than that in a competitive labour market, and could therefore raise productivity and aggregate demand, and profits, and investment. The proposition that employees should be protected is not therefore immediately one of higher costs.

Even the provision via employers of welfare benefits in addition to pay through national insurance schemes or healthcare and unemployment insurance agreements is potentially something which could improve productivity overall. Such schemes, which tend to work through payments taken directly from wages, represent an efficient form of government intervention in employment markets and are less complicated than tax credits or complicated forms of subsidy.

On this basis, intervention in near-employment markets, such as the provision of broadband so that employees can work productively from home, or the subsidy and regulation of childcare so that the supply of labour expands, are capable of being seen as both protecting employees, boosting productivity, and benefitting employers more than the taxes or minor inflationary pressures involved might increase costs. As in all things, a balanced approach by government in consideration of employers and employees could deliver the conditions for a thriving and more than functional economy.

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

To what extent do specialisation and the division of labour address the basic economic problem?

  1.   The basic economic problem illustrates the difficulty caused by the fact that economic goods are limited and subject to resource constraints but wants are unlimited. A choice therefore must be made, which gives rise to opportunity cost. Specialisation seeks to lower costs and thereby improve productivity by increasing the quantity and quality of output from firms. It does this by concentrating individuals or economic enterprises (or occasionally whole economies) on particular parts of the production or supply chain. This is often accompanied by the division of labour, in which individual workers or small teams of workers focus on particular aspects of the production process for a good or service. If correctly carried out, specialisation increases output and efficiency, leading to gains in terms of welfare and pareto efficiency for societies (shown by the outward movement of a production possibility curve.) It can also lead to lower costs, and possibly to production ...

Inequality, Part One: the greatest market failure?

    Income inequality arises when different consumers have different incomes, and different people have different talents. It could also arise because of the source of income or the value of the talents. For instance, employees might have different incomes from each other because of different marginal labour products, different factor returns to their labour, or different elasticities of labour. People might have different skills for which there is a greater or lesser need and employers, or the purchasers of labour might have different demands. Equally, entrepreneurs often take greater risks than others, and thereby expect and receive greater rewards than those who do not take risks. There might be different factor returns to capital or land, which result in various levels of profit, dividend, or rent, for those who do not live by the return to their labour value. A functional market would bring all these diverse groups together as suppliers and consumers and would matc...

Is the existence of different wages a problem for societies, and if so, how can it be remedied?

  Adam Smith, and Karl Marx, both believed that labour value lies at the heart of all economic value. Commodities, goods, and services arise from the interaction of land, labour, and capital. Since Land is fixed until new land is cleared or built by workers, and since capital enhances labour and is invented by people, they both thought that the only people who added value in economic transactions were workers. This theory of labour value was qualified in the second half of the twentieth century by the elevation of entrepreneurialism as a factor of production. The enterprising businesspeople who took on risks, brought factors together, and who were rewarded with profit having been prepared to make losses, were elevated to a ‘fourth factor.’ This idea makes some sense, but also serves to undermine the idea that labour value on its own creates economic value. If labour has value, some argue that the value of time taken from a life to work should be viewed equally. This means t...