A firm’s costs are made up of fixed and variable costs. Fixed costs do not change with output, and therefore fall when averaged. Variable costs do change with output, and will eventually always increase because of rising marginal costs, which in turn cause returns to diminish with each extra item of output before becoming negative. The lowest point of each short-run average cost curve forms a point on the long-run average cost curve (the short run being the period when at least one factor of production is fixed and the long run being that when all factors can be varied.)
It follows that there
will be a point on the Long-run average cost curve when a firm reaches its
lowest LRAC, and that the LRAC will have been falling as each successive SRAC
falls ‘downwards’ along it. The explanation
for why this process occurs is not linked to any one cause, and could involve
falls in wage, raw material, regulatory, or business costs. They could also be the result of economies of
scale resulting from the enlargement of the business.
At the level of an
industry, which is made up of firms, such falls in costs are more likely to be
the result of innovation transferring from one firm to others because of a lack
of legal or information barriers, an increase in the number of firms in the
market, or falling wage, legal, or resource costs. Any of these factors could
also increase productivity, which is a figure arrived at by dividing the value
of factor output by the cost of factor input in a given time.
If for instance wage
costs fell because the government changed the taxes employers have to pay to
employ people, such as national insurance in the UK, or because there were more
workers looking for jobs who were prepared to accept a lower wage, the cost of
labour would fall, but the output would almost certainly remain the same, leading
to higher productivity. Equally, if workers or capital became more productive
and output rose across an industry, average costs would fall, caeteris paribus
since average costs are calculated according to output.
Costs help define
profits. Profit is the difference between revenue and cost, whether in total,
on average or at the margin. An industry in which firms found that marginal
costs fell, for instance, but marginal revenue remained the same—a free market
in the short run—would produce where MC=MR, but make money where AR was greater
than AC. A difference would be an abnormal profit. In the short run, this would
be good for firms, but not necessarily for consumers since they would be paying
a price higher than marginal cost, transferring their consumer surplus to
companies, and living in an economy which was not allocating resources
efficiently in terms of welfare or production.
This situation could
resolve itself, however. A free market has no barriers to information or
knowledge, and many firms in it. If costs fell, eventually some firms would be
first movers and lower price, and consumers would then flock to them, other
suppliers would copy them, and all supply would increase. Consumers would
benefit and so would the whole economy, assuming no externalities, because
everyone would be getting more goods, more cheaply.
Markets are usually
not perfect, however. If an oligopoly or monopoly (and even more a natural
monopoly) experienced falling costs across an industry, the firms involved
might be just as likely to keep the difference between costs and revenue in
terms of profit. Their shareholders might in fact force them their directors to
do that, as owners seeking a dividend. In that event, consumers would not
necessarily benefit.
Situations in which
large companies make such large profits rarely last, however. In the very long
run, large profits might be partially turned into a profit-satisficing level of
cost in which firms diverted some of the money gained into things which are either
fixed costs—like research and development, advertising, marketing, or mergers
and acquisitions—or variable ones, like wages and worker compensation. This
could result in more productivity, the reduction of externalities, a greater
market in which global competition and development becomes possible, or the
development of products, services, and supply chains which are secure and
robust and benefit consumers in ways other than simple low prices.
Very large falls in
industry costs leading to high profits might also encourage windfall taxes and
government intervention which pays down national debt or lowers taxes
elsewhere, leading to higher growth, more redistribution of income, or more
public goods. These things could in theory encourage the growth of national
welfare and allocative efficiency in a sophisticated society, and reduce
dependency ratios.
Comments
Post a Comment