Skip to main content

Will a profit-making firm cease to exist if it makes losses?

 

Profit is a positive difference between revenue and cost. Firms maximise profit where they neither make nor lose money on the last item produced and sold. This is the level of production where marginal cost is equal to marginal revenue. The actual amount of profit in such circumstances will be defined by the difference between average cost and average revenue at that level of production. 

Economics also makes a distinction between normal, break-even, and abnormal (sometimes called supernormal) profits. Normal profit is the level of profit at which a firm covers its opportunity cost, usually defined as what it could have earned by doing something else with its money in the same time period. Break-even is an accounting concept in which a firm’s revenues are equal to its costs and is usually treated as the same thing as normal profit by economists. Abnormal profit is what most people understand as profit, which is a surplus of cash over spending.

Economic theory does not assume that firms will maximise profits, it assumes that maximising profits is the most rational thing firms can do in most circumstances. All value is labour value, but bringing labour, capital, and land together in an enterprise is something entrepreneurs and companies need an incentive to do, which in most cases is the potential profit to be made.

Firms might have other objectives.  For instance, they could try to sell everything in their inventory for any revenue, as sandwich shops tend do at the end of the day, or beach clothing stores do at the end of the summer season. This would ensure that all stock was at least sold for something, even if little or no money was made on the good and would avoid the item in question being wasted. It would also raise money if the firm needed it quickly for a loan or rent payment. This tactic is called revenue maximisation and occurs where MR=0.

Equally, a firm may decide to maximise its sales, by producing at the point where AC=AR. This might allow the firm to flood the market, displace a competitor, or gain useful complementary sales.

All of these options are available to firms, but in the long run, the aim for any business which is neither a charity nor a folly should rationally be to maximise profit. In some market structures there is no choice; perfect competition in the long run does not allow firms which wish to continue in operation to do anything else. Monopolies and oligopolies may have some discretion, and choose, for instance, profit-satisficing, but directors and shareholders will still usually demand some move towards profit rather than revenue or sales.

If revenue does not cover costs, firms are making a loss. The decision as to whether to shut down is not an easy one, however. This is because costs are made up of fixed and variable elements. Average fixed costs fall with output. They represent expenditures which are not associated with output, such as, for instance, ‘overhead’ costs of power, water and utilities, salaries, rents, or payments on loans. It is possible that a firm which can make some contribution to these things, even if it does not pay them in full for a matter of weeks or months, can survive so long as it can eventually find the money. For instance, a landlord might take three months and incur considerable expenditure to remove one commercial tenant and gain new ones, and so might accept one month of partial or no payment.

By contrast, firms which cannot cover variable costs are dead in the water. Variable costs are costs that relate directly to output, such as wages for workers, the cost of raw materials, and the maintenance of machinery related to its use. If firms cannot pay for these items, they cannot produce.

It follows that a firm making a loss, but able to cover average variable costs in the short run by the earnings from reduced revenues, can survive for a time, even if it can only make a small contribution to fixed costs. Firms unable to pay average variable costs must shut down unless subsidised from elsewhere. Such subsidy might come from being part of a wider and more productive group, though will be subject to considerations of wider objectives by the larger body. Similarly, a government could in theory choose to subsidise a firm which cannot cover costs for its own reasons, such as a pandemic, a crisis, the strategic importance of jobs and production to the wider economy, or to allow the firm to grow from ‘infant’ status.

It follows that most firms will act to maximise profits, but will neither automatically do so, nor automatically shut down if it fails to do so.

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Domestic Demand, External Pressures, and Inflation

    Domestic Demand refers to the accumulated (that is, aggregate) demand within all the markets of an economy. As such, it can be handily summed up in a formula, C+I+G+X-M, where C is consumption, I is investment, G is net government spending, and X-M is net exports. This is usually referred to as ‘AD.’ Consumption is the largest part of AD. All the consumption decisions within the economy, including all non-investment purchases by households, individuals, and firms, add up to around two thirds of AD. In addition, the Keynesian economic theory asserts that there is a link between consumption and investment, which can drive AD upwards, as firms invest more when they see that consumers are purchasing more goods and services. Investment is a sustained addition to long-run aggregate supply, or capital for short. AD can be plotted against LRAS on a two-dimensional graph. If AD and LRAS meet at the point where there is maximum real GDP/GNI with no tendency for the price level to rise, t

Understanding the Balance of Payments

The balance of payments is the measure of all economic transactions between an economy and the rest of the world. As such, it covers the whole economy and should not be confused with the Government Budget. The balance of payments must always balance and if there is a deficit or surplus in goods, services, or some other component of the balance, it will be met with an equal change in the value of money or other asset. In a free exchange market, for instance, the currency of the country will adjust to alter living standards and the source of any surplus or deficit. The balance of payments consists of a current account, known as the balance of trade , a financial account , and a capital account. The current account is a record of net exports, plus income from abroad and direct transfers into a country. Many countries, particularly in the English-speaking world, run a deficit on this current account, because consumers and businesses purchase more imports than exports. This may well

Higher Energy Prices and The Economy

  Energy prices are a basic cost. They are semi-variable for most businesses, in that a basic fixed cost of energy is generated by the need to heat or to cool buildings, and to carry out operations. In addition, a marginal cost exists for producers in terms of the energy required to increase production. Finally, energy costs are also built into the transport of raw materials, and the distribution of finished goods and services, which again contribute to marginal costs. If global energy prices are rising wholesale, it is unlikely that businesses or individuals will be able to lower the retail cost of energy by switching between suppliers. Energy storage is expensive and encourages economies of scale and oligopolies, in which consumer choice is limited at times of higher wholesale prices. When energy prices are low, smaller companies can purchase wholesale and make money at the margin undercutting bigger companies as storage costs will be a burden for the latter and the small companies