Skip to main content

Should a firm which produces a product with a positive income elasticity of demand and positive cross elasticity of demand lower the price of the product?

 

1.

Income elasticity of demand assesses the degree to which a change in income will affect the demand for a good. Positive income elasticity of demand suggests that a rise in income will result in a rise in demand, and a fall in income in a fall in demand.

If a firm is a price-maker rather than a price taker (that is, if it is not operating under conditions of perfect competition) then it might choose to reduce price to make its product affordable. This suggests that the good would have a positive price elasticity of demand too, because otherwise, a fall in price could result in a loss of revenue.

A positive cross elasticity of demand indicates that a good has substitutes which could experience a fall in demand if the good is reduced in price. This implies, but does not prove, that the good itself would attract customers from the substitute. This would allow for a rise in revenue, the capture of greater market share, and, possibly, the development of economies of scale as long run average costs would decline with greater output. In these circumstances, cutting prices would be justified.

If the firm were operating or monopolistic competition, however, starting a price war with other firms or even making customers price-aware could collapse the whole market, and shift firms towards normal profit, so the decision would have to be weighted carefully. Firms in an oligopoly would also have to consider the response of other firms before acting. This is because the demand curve, equivalent to the average revenue curve, is kinked in oligopolistic markets, with price inelastic consumers below the kink. If a firm cut prices and people did not change their activity, large falls in revenue could result; if consumers became price-aware and changed habit, inertial behaviour, or tastes, the increase in their price elasticity could be disastrous.

The nature of the good could be a factor. A good with a positive income elasticity of demand is not an inferior good, but it could be a Veblen good (that is, one in conspicuous consumption.) Consumers who buy goods for reasons of quality rather than simply price, or because price is high, might not react well when confronted with advertising or marketing simply based on low prices, as the activities of Sainsbury’s food stores in the 2000s, and those of Marks and Spencers stores in the 2010s, show. Both companies were retail giants who launched a ‘value to shout about’ campaign in one instance, and a line of cheap clothing in another, which damaged their brand, drove away traditional customers, and failed to gain new ones.

The objectives of the firm might also matter. Firms which seek to revenue maximise or sales maximise are not seeking to produce at maximum profit and might consider the expansion of revenue or sales as a success. Many newspapers and television shows earn more money from advertising based on the number of readers or viewers they have rather than from the quality of their product or the revenue from customers paying directly, for instance. 

Firms generally consider the direction of the wider economy before making decisions. In an economy in which credit is restricted or unemployment is rising, some firms may choose to cut prices to increase revenue or simply to sell goods which might soon become unaffordable. If on the other hand, firms were confident about the future they would not act like this, choosing instead to leave price rises to inflation or below and to rely on the expansion of the market through rising incomes.

Sometimes a firm will not have the capacity to increase output to meet new demand at a lower price, and in these circumstances a fall in price will result, unless the firm has large amounts of product in storage ready to be released, in a fall in revenue. Raising production might raise costs, which, at a time when revenue is falling, simply means a move towards a normal profit or a loss, either of which would have to be explained to owners, shareholders, or creditors.  Firms therefore might have no incentive to lower prices.

Therefore, firms with positive income elasticity of demand and positive cross-elasticity of demand should first identify the price elasticity of demand of their consumers; note the market structure in which they operate and consider how rivals will act before deciding to change prices. They will also have to consider if their activity will result in temporary or permanent falls in revenue, what their capacity is, and how stakeholders will react before acting.

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Domestic Demand, External Pressures, and Inflation

    Domestic Demand refers to the accumulated (that is, aggregate) demand within all the markets of an economy. As such, it can be handily summed up in a formula, C+I+G+X-M, where C is consumption, I is investment, G is net government spending, and X-M is net exports. This is usually referred to as ‘AD.’ Consumption is the largest part of AD. All the consumption decisions within the economy, including all non-investment purchases by households, individuals, and firms, add up to around two thirds of AD. In addition, the Keynesian economic theory asserts that there is a link between consumption and investment, which can drive AD upwards, as firms invest more when they see that consumers are purchasing more goods and services. Investment is a sustained addition to long-run aggregate supply, or capital for short. AD can be plotted against LRAS on a two-dimensional graph. If AD and LRAS meet at the point where there is maximum real GDP/GNI with no tendency for the price level to rise, t

Higher Energy Prices and The Economy

  Energy prices are a basic cost. They are semi-variable for most businesses, in that a basic fixed cost of energy is generated by the need to heat or to cool buildings, and to carry out operations. In addition, a marginal cost exists for producers in terms of the energy required to increase production. Finally, energy costs are also built into the transport of raw materials, and the distribution of finished goods and services, which again contribute to marginal costs. If global energy prices are rising wholesale, it is unlikely that businesses or individuals will be able to lower the retail cost of energy by switching between suppliers. Energy storage is expensive and encourages economies of scale and oligopolies, in which consumer choice is limited at times of higher wholesale prices. When energy prices are low, smaller companies can purchase wholesale and make money at the margin undercutting bigger companies as storage costs will be a burden for the latter and the small companies

Understanding the Balance of Payments

The balance of payments is the measure of all economic transactions between an economy and the rest of the world. As such, it covers the whole economy and should not be confused with the Government Budget. The balance of payments must always balance and if there is a deficit or surplus in goods, services, or some other component of the balance, it will be met with an equal change in the value of money or other asset. In a free exchange market, for instance, the currency of the country will adjust to alter living standards and the source of any surplus or deficit. The balance of payments consists of a current account, known as the balance of trade , a financial account , and a capital account. The current account is a record of net exports, plus income from abroad and direct transfers into a country. Many countries, particularly in the English-speaking world, run a deficit on this current account, because consumers and businesses purchase more imports than exports. This may well